Beginning the Puzzle:
Sources, Couples, and Private Enforcement in Early Irish Law
Finding a reliable description of the laws of
pre-Christian Ireland has been nearly impossible until the last fifty
years. Only recently have a few of
the texts begun to be at all reliably translated due to a variety of
difficulties with the texts. The Irish
law tracts, often called the Brehon laws (the Brehons were the Irish judges),
were recorded around the sixth or seventh centuries, likely by early Christian
monks. By the eighth century, the
texts were viewed as sacrosanct and unchangeable; they could be interpreted by
the judges, but not altered by them.
Irish law in these surviving tracts is a jurist-made law. Neither king nor subjects had influence
in its development.[1]
The first challenge to analyzing the legal
tracts is a linguistic one. Surviving
texts are written in Old Irish – a dialect unknown to even Middle or
Modern Irish speakers – and many of the legal terms appear only in the
law texts. In addition, the texts
have glosses and commentaries written in Latin, Middle Irish and even Modern
Irish that can sometimes help in translating the Old Irish, but that mostly
hinder translations.[2] While the texts began to be translated
in the mid-nineteenth century, the Irish scholars at the time were ill-prepared
to reliably translate the texts. Consequently,
the multi-volume translation Ancient Laws of Ireland, was often misleading
and inaccurate. This translation,
however, is what scholarship regarding the early Irish laws was based on for
almost 100 years. Initial scholars wrote
based on the translation, and then subsequent scholars wrote off of those initial
commentaries. Any translation prior
to 1920 is not reliable; I would move that even further to the 1950s or
1980s. A leading Irish scholar,
D.A. Binchy, published in the mid-twentieth century a collection of the Irish
texts in the old Irish, making the tracts accessible to any scholar willing to
tackle the translation again.
Ideas that Binchy did consider to be accurately
translated from the texts are: Òinstitutions of solidarity of kindred,
ÔclientshipÕ as a forerunner of feudal commendation, pignoris capio and
ÔfastingÕ as methods of execution, and the organization of a complex system of
suretyship as a primitive substitute for the public enforcement of legal
obligations.Ó[3] Binchy also cautions that the Irish
legal texts, like all early legal texts, should not be taken too literally;
that the tracts reflect an abstract schematic, even within the details, that
could never have existed in everyday life.
Though the presentation is conventionalized, however, the general
outlines are still true and we can still learn a great deal about the
institutions under which the early Irish lived.[4] It is also important to remember that
law tracts from different schools around Ireland reflect different laws and
customs from different areas; each law tract does not represent a uniform code
for all of the early Irish geographically or temporally. The tracts are uniform, however, in
their style, composition, and technical terminology. As mentioned, many terms do not exist
outside of the legal realm, which itself adds evidence that the Brehons alone
were familiar with the terms and legal language, preserving their importance to
the community as they maintained the mystery of the laws.[5]
Despite the effort of the English to impose
their common law system on the Irish, aspects of the Brehon law remained until
at least the 1600s beyond The Pale of English influence. With the Irish revolution at the
beginning of the 20th century came a revival of Celtic enthusiasm,
and some court cases from the decades following reference the Brehon laws, for
instance: Foyle and Bann Fisheries
Ltd. v. Attorney General (1949) 83 I.L.T.R. 29; R. (Moore) v. OÕHanrahan (1927)
I.R. 406; Little v. Cooper (1937) I.R. 1.[6] But trying to revive the laws became
problematic within the courts, as this excerpt from one of the cases states:
The law still has to be deduced from elliptical,
incomplete and often corrupt texts, which appear to be copies of copies of
archaic manuscripts, reproduced by much later hereditary scholars, to the accompaniment
of unreliable and often unskilled and sometimes unscrupulous
interpretations. The study of Irish
law, seriously undertaken only in recent times, is still in its infancy and the
conclusions of the most experienced scholars are tentative, and seem at best
generally to represent plausible historical speculation. Dr. DillonÕs view is that the law texts
cannot be used as a solid basis for any conclusion at all until they are edited
and examined.[7]
But while utilizing the early Irish laws for
modern legal purposes will prove difficult at least until the texts have been
reliably translated, there are still comparative historical and legal purposes
for revealing the contents of the texts.
While they have some fairly easily identifiable Christian glosses, the
texts were not Christianized to the same extent as Anglo-Saxon law. Unlike under the Anglo-Saxon kings,
there was no central authority in Ireland for introducing and enforcing
reforms. To alter traditional law
in Ireland, the monks needed the cooperation of the Brehons; and the Brehons
were not eager to give up their power.[8]
C‡in L‡namna- The Law of Couples
The
C‡in L‡namna is one of the Irish law tracts from around the 7th
century. This particular text
listed laws related to marital and parental legal relationships. This is one of the texts of which we
have a recently translated version from a peer-confirmed reliable translator.[9] The laws are brief and sometimes
somewhat confusing in their syntax, but they reveal some otherwise unknown
aspects of the rights of woman from a primary source.
There
are ten types of relationships for cohabitation and procreation described in
the text. Common to all, however,
are some general principles that are described before the specifics of the
different relationships.
Exempt from legal suit for each is what each may
have used or have consumed as against the other, except what lien, obligation or
loan may have imposed, or what one of them may have mis-appropriated from the
other. Exempt from legal suit is everything useful to the partnership,
everything done in good faith; liable to legal claim is everything done
in bad faith in the law of the couple.
Essentially,
when a couple in a relationship splits, one party may try to retain more goods
than the law provides that party is allowed. This first law provides that the wronged
party only has a legal claim to items used or gained by the other in bad
faith. In the course of a
relationship, goods are used and contracts are made in good faith; these items
cannot be disputed or sought in litigation.
The
next general law sets out the types of legal pairings to be found in Irish law:
Question. How many pairings are there in Irish
law? Answer. Eight: a lord and his base clients, a church and its tenantry, a
father and his daughter, a girl and her brother, a son and his mother, a
foster-son and his foster-mother, a teacher and his pupil, a man and his wife.
It
is not immediately clear to what this law pertains in a text about couples;
perhaps these ÔpairingsÕ are the types of relationships to which the general
rules apply, and the rest of the laws specific to male-female pairings are
sub-rules for the last group, Òa man and his wife.Ó
The
final general law further describes the division of property; rather, what can
and cannot be litigated, and what remedies a party has against the other.
Equally exempt from legal suit for each is whatever one of them may have given the other, whatever one of them may have used as against the other, without violent crime, without stealth. Everything taken without permission that is complained about is repaid by simple replacement of the object until the matter goes as far as the legal remedy of fasting, except in the case of the church. Repayment, by simple replacement, of what is taken without permission and complained about is all that is required until there is evasion of the legal obligations that arise from fasting, or legal default. Anything taken by stealth, by violent crime, anything taken without permission, that is complained about and ignored, is levied with its penalty fine.
Essentially,
if something was taken without permission, and the other party complained about
it, the first party need only replace the item. If, however, the first party tries to
evade its legal obligations by not replacing the item, or if the item was taken
by stealth or violent crime, then a penalty fine is added to the replacement.
Moving
on to the more specific laws related to cohabitating couples and procreation,
the first of these laws describes the ten specific types of legally recognized
relationships:
Question: how many couples of cohabitation and procreation are there in Irish law? Answer: ten-(1) union of common contribution; (2) union of a woman on a man's contribution; (3) union of a man on a woman's contribution with service; (4) union of a woman who accepts a man's solicitation; (5) union of a man who visits the woman, without work, without solicitation, without provision, without material contribution; (6) union by abduction; (7) union of wandering mercenaries; (8) union by criminal seduction; (9) union by rape; (10) union of mockery.
These ten types of relationships
are addressed in more detail in the following laws. The first is the Òunion of common
contributionÓ when the man and woman come to the union as equals.
(1) Union of common contribution: if it is a union with land and stock and household equipment, and if their marital relationship is one of equal status and equal propriety-and such a woman is called a woman of joint dominion-no contract of either is valid without the consent of the other, except for contracts that benefit their establishment. These are: an agreement for common ploughing with proper kinsmen when they do not themselves have a full ploughing team; paying for the leasing of land; getting together food for a coshering; getting food for feast-days; paying stud fees; fitting out the household; making an agreement for joint husbandry; the purchase of any essentials that they lack. Every contract shall be without neglect, an advantageous contract, conscientious, in accordance with right and propriety, with acknowledgement on both sides that the ownership of what is acquired belongs to the person whose property was alienated to acquire it.
In a marriage of common contribution, the consent of both spouses was necessary for the formation of certain contracts. Those contracts which were excepted were specifically described. In addition, the law includes that agreements shall be made in good faith. Further, as the next law specifies, if the lack of an item will bring a loss to the household, it cannot be sold without the agreement of both spouses:
Anything, the lack of which brings loss on the household, cannot be sold without common counsel, consultation, and mutual concession. For the impairment of the joint economy in a union of common contribution is not proper without mutual concession.
Interestingly, it is social policy that pushes the equal rights of both spouses in the union of common contribution. Similarly, the law regarding the fosterage of children of a common contribution household is also related to policy:
Putting children in a well-befriended and good fosterage is a contract in accord with all propriety that brings well-being into the community of their common household.
The following are the remainder of the laws set out for a union of common contribution. These laws describe the rights of the woman and the man in contracts, divorce, and the partition of proceeds. Note the rights of the women and the extent to which she is treated an equal in this type of marriage.
Every contract shall be without cheating. Either of them may dissolve the bad contracts of the other. The one does not dissolve the good contracts of the other in the case of those matters that have been listed, if the joint husbandry is without mutual friction, without mutual inculpation, in good partnership, in good faith.
If they divorce, each divorce shall be without mutual defrauding. If they divorce by mutual consent, let them divide their property in accordance with legal propriety.
A third of all proceeds belongs to the owner of the land, except for handiwork; a third of the cattle dropped during the union belongs to the owner of the stock from which they are sprung; a third to whoever did the labour. Division is made in proportion to the entitlement of each in regard to land, stock and labour. If the conduct of each is equally good or equally bad, this is the way they divide their thirds.
The third assigned to labour of the proceeds of the cattle is further divided into thirds: a third to the master of the house, a third to the mistress of the house, a third to the workers, that is, the herders.
Likewise dairy produce: it is divided in three between land 12/36, stock 12/36 and labour 12/36. The labour third: half goes to the woman who does the work 6/36; a twelfth goes to dairy vessels 3/36; two-thirds of the remaining half go to the master of the house 2/36, a third to the dairy workers 1/36.
If one of them is ill-behaved, the labour portion of the ill-behaved falls to the well-behaved, but the portions due to land and stock are not diminished
The labour third of the fodder corn and salt meat: let it be divided in three i.e. a third 1/9 to the wife who is responsible for ploughing and reaping and for looking after the pig-sties, for feeding and for fattening the pigs, unless they are fattened on milk. In that case, the wife gets two-thirds 2/9. For only spring-work in regard to ploughing and looking after the sties, the wife is entitled to two-thirds of a third 2/27.
The wife takes a half of clothing and of woven fabric, a third of fibre combed and ready for spinning; a sixth of fleeces and sheaves of flax; a third of woad in steeping vats, half if it is caked.
Anything that either of them may consume that belongs to the other is exempt from liability if it is by mutual consent. Whence is said: Without penalty is anything mutually discussed, mutually conceded.
Every defrauding is paid off by replacement in kind unless the person entitled waives claim, or else compensation is paid on the day of parting.
Anything taken by stealth, or despite mild or forceful protest, or by violent seizure, is repaid with its interest and with double its replacement if dry goods; if it is livestock, it is repaid with milk and young, with double replacement, and with interest.
Exempt from liability is every loan, every lease, every sale, every purchase, without mutual defrauding by either, made with the private property of each up to the amount of the honour-price of each, in accordance with the contracting rights of each.
Hospitality and refection is a duty of each of them according to rank. [...] Each of them gives hospitality to his/her own lord, to his/her own church and friends and relations.
In many decisions, the wifeÕs opinion is of equal importance to the husbandÕs. In terms of property division, women (not necessarily the wife) get sometimes a half and sometimes a share in goods created through her labor. While women may in general not enjoy equal rights to men, they do receive more rights than a medieval image often allows them.
Next the laws describe the rights of a man and woman in a union in which the man brings more, a Òunion on manÕs contribution.Ó The word ÒcŽtmuinterÓ refers to a chief wife (as opposed to a concubine or secondary wife).
Union on man's contribution: (2) Union of a woman on a man's contribution: the man's contract is a valid contract without the wife's consent, except for the sale of clothing and food; and the sale of cattle and sheep, if she is a duly contracted wife who is not a cŽtmuinter.
If she is a woman who is a proper cŽtmuinter, equally good and equally well-bred — for everyone of equal goodness is of equal birth — she impugns all his contracts if they are foolish — for immunity from suit does not attach to defrauding and to what is forcefully protested against — and her sureties annul them.
If he gives bridewealth to acquire another woman, even from his own private property, that bridewealth is forfeit to his cŽtmuinter if she carries out her marital obligations. Every secondary wife who comes 'over the head' of a cŽtmuinter is liable to penalty: she pays the honour-price of the cŽtmuinter.
The wife gives hospitality to half as many people as her husband, in accordance with the social status of her husband.
[...]Everybody is fed and hospitality is not refused up to the legal number of his/her retinue. Refusal of hospitality in the case of a guest accompanied by a excessive retinue does not damage one's honour for, though one refuse, this is not deemed refusal of hospitality if the retinue is excessive.
If they divorce and the divorce is by mutual consent and their behaviour is equally good at the time of parting, what the one may have freely consumed as against the other is without penalty at the time of parting if it is done without bad faith and with consent, so that they may not defraud each other. Every replacement in kind shall be as that consumed, with milk and young and dung and with interest. Everything taken by stealth, by force, by secret removal, without consent, without recompense, without asking pardon, is levied with its penalty fine.
The wife receives half the handiwork, as we said in the first type of union we discussed; a sixth of the dairy produce with the same proportions as previously between land and cows and vessels and servants. She receives ~a ninth of the cattle dropped during the union, a ninth of the corn, and a ninth of the salt meat, if she is a great worker.
She receives a sack of corn for every month that remains until the year end i.e. until the first of May next, following the time they part.
Even when a wife contributes little to the initial union, she still retains influence over some contracts entered into by her husband. She has rights, if a chief wife, over the secondary wives and she has rights upon divorce to a portion of the goods produced.
Next we examine what changes when a woman brings more to a union than the man: a Òunion of an heiressÓ.
Union of an heiress: (3) Union of a man on a woman's contribution: in that case, the husband goes in the track of the wife and wife in the track of the husband. If he is a man of service he receives a ninth of the corn; and of the salt meat, if he is a 'head of counsel' who controls the people of the household with advice of equal standing. The sixth of milk produce is divided in two: one half (1/12) goes to the vessels; of the other half, the husband receives two-thirds (1/18). He receives a ninth of the handicraft when they divorce. If they divorce by mutual consent, they part in this way.
If either of them is badly behaved, the labour third of the badly-behaved partner is forfeit to the well-behaved one. In the case of a cŽtmuinter, everything is forfeit to the party that carries out his/her marital duties, apart from what the other is entitled to in respect of land and breeding stock. But they part as they came together: what survives of what each brought in to the other, that is what each brings away on parting, or its replacement out of the profits if it no longer survives.
But he is a husband who is paid honour-price in accordance with his wife's status if she holds all the property, unless he has higher property qualifications in his own right than his wife or is more godly, more high-born or more estimable than she.
Here, upon dissolution, each leaves with the property he or she brought to the union that remains. The man receives a portion of goods produces, but these laws are instead written to specify what portion the man receives rather than the portion the woman receives as in the prior laws.
The following laws describe other types of unions and the affirmative rights that exist in those scenarios. The first two seem to cover unions perhaps more informal than the first, or perhaps when neither party can contribute to the initial union.
Other Unions: (5) Union of a man who visits the woman, without provision without work: a fifth of the handiwork is the portion of the man (i.e. of the partner) when they part if the handiwork is hers to dispose of-for a fifth is the proportion of the compensation due to him for her being dishonoured; if an offence is committed against her, that is the compensation he is paid for it.
(4) Union on accepting the inducement of the man: in that case the man receives a quarter of her handiwork. If it is a union with stock on land, let them divide by the proportions of land, labour and breeding stock, in accordance with what each owns.
When these unions dissolve, the man retains a proportion of the handiwork of the woman if it is hers to give. These unions seem to involve consent on the part of the woman, because the following rules contrast in that there is no consent by the woman (or in the case of Òunion in secret,Ó of her family). The word ÒŽraicÕ refers to the body honor price.
(6/8) Union by abduction and union in secret: they have no stock or dry goods to divide on parting, only offspring. If a woman abducted from her family grants property to her partner who has abducted her, that grant is invalid from the point of view of her family and it is thus repaid: it is paid off with half penalty-fine if what was given belonged to the woman; if a third party owns a share in it, it is paid off with full penalty-fine. The same holds good for union by criminal seduction in secret.
(9) Union by rape or by stealth: they the partners possess nothing but offspring. Full Žraic is paid for a virgin, for a young nun who does not reject her veil, and for a cŽtmuinter; half Žraic for secondary wives— all this is without the cooperation of the woman— together with the full honour price of the man of highest rank who has authority over her of those to whom she specially belongs.
In these unions, no property exists to divide because the union had no legal support to property, and because all that was produced recognized by the law are offspring. The final law describes a cruel union created for the amusement of others: a Òunion of mockeryÓ. Here, someone has brought together a mentally handicapped man and woman. The law provides for the care of any offspring:
(10) Union of mockery: union of a lunatic or madman with a deranged woman or madwoman. Neither of them is bound to take or to make payments. The person who brings them together for fun and the responsible person in whose presence this takes place, theirs is the offspring, if offspring there be; its rearing, compensation for its offences, and its suretyship falls on both of them. The Žraic and the legacy of such persons is divided between the king, the church and the family.Ó[10]
Whoever brings the two together or has knowledge of the
union is responsible for any offspring produced. This responsibility includes raising the
children, paying for the childrenÕs offenses, and supporting the children when
they enter into suretyship arrangements.
Since the parents likely cannot provide such complex duties for their
children, the law supports these children being provided for.
State or Private Enforcement?
While
some evidence exists that the king played a role in some disputes, those
disputes seem limited to disputes involving the king himself. Disputes within kin groups were
arbitrated by independent judges who interpreted the laws but had no means of
enforcement. It was up to
individuals to enforce judgments by means of fasting or cattle raiding if the
other party was not paying. But
lest we make the same mistake as the Victorian anthropologist and impose the
idea that our society reflects the epitome of culture and hold the early Irish
legal system as inferior and anarchic, letÕs consider the society as a whole
and the role of the law in it.
In
a society that at the same time is rural, hierarchical, familiar, and Òtribal,Ó
there was not in existence a system that could support the development of the
judicial, administrative, and political institutions which we find in our
States now. The tœath was small, both in population and
in the geographic area it covered and influence it held, and so there was no need
for an intermediate group between the king and subjects. In addition, cities and walled towns
were brought to Ireland by invaders; the early Irish people did not have these
places of mass congregation that supported cities and marketplaces. Remember that the very words we use
– politics, civilization, etc.—reflect the urban roots of our own
society.[11] In an aristocratic and rural society,
like that of the early Irish, it is quite possible, owing to the system of
patronage, to produce great literature and artÉ but it is not possible to
develop a Òpolity,Ó as the Greeks called it, because the pattern of life is not
complex enough to demand it. Within
each tœath, the king, with the aid of
a few officers, could practice the few functions of government necessary in
person. Essentially, the idea of
the State as something distinct form the ruler, or of the kingÕs government as
distinct from the king (the idea of depersonalization of institutions) would be
foreign to the minds of the early Irish.[12]
Rather than the responsibility of the king, the
kin-group itself was responsible for its own internal conflicts. Early Irish society was based on
agnostic kin-groups. Originally,
the narrowest kin-group was called derbfhine,
and described four generations.
This was the property owning unit, and was responsible for the
liabilities of its members. Like
all known early systems, the law did not bother legislating amongst the
internal affairs of the kindred; instead, the law would be limited between
members of different kin-groups.[13]
During these intertribal relations, it was the
king who mattered. The king made
war against other kings (ÒwarÓ generally described cattle raiding) or made
treaties with them. The king made
submission to an over-king, to whom he gave tribute and hostages. He acquired these hostages and tribute
from his own subjects, for which he was personally responsible. When it came to internal government,
however, the king did not have the power to create new laws or repeal existing
laws; the traditional rules of law, as mentioned, were completely out of his
control and were instead interpreted by Brehons. Granted, a Òroyal judgeÓ (a Brehon
chosen by the king) existed in each tœath,
but he seems to have had jurisdiction only over issues like treason and taxation:
issues where the kingÕs rights were involved. It is here one can see the beginnings of
public law. Aside from this limited
area, however, there was no state-administered justice.[14]
According to Binchy, there is no evidence in the
texts themselves that the king would, if necessary, enforce a judgment in an
ordinary dispute between families in his tœath. Binchy attributes the lack of public
enforcement of judgments to the idea that those legal disputes likely to arise
between members of separate family groups were likely few in number and kind,
given that the separate family groups lived isolated on hereditary land. Other than crimes and torts like
manslaughter, maiming, arson, theft, insult, and trespass, there would be title
problems to immoveable property and problems with those basic contractual
relationships that could develop in a society that lacked urban market places
and a case nexus—these two institutions are the Òprimary engines of
development for the law of obligations.Ó
Were litigation restricted to those crimes, there would be so few of
them that one might argue they did not justify the effort in establishing the
machinery to enforce the judgment—it wouldnÕt have paid to do so. The original reason for publicly
administered justice was to get money for the kingÕs treasury; with so few
cases, the cost of administering such a process would not likely justify the
rewards.[15]
When suits arose within the tœath between members of different kindreds, even in cases of
homicide, the State (king) took no part.
The kinsmen of the slain or otherwise wronged party could either
prosecute the blood feud against the offenderÕs kin or else agree with the
offenderÕs kin that the customary compensation should be paid or else the case
would be submitted to arbitration by a Brehon. When submitting to a Brehon, both sides
agree in advance to accept the judgment and to be bound by it. The party who wins the judgment received
no assistance from a public authority since, as mentioned, private rights were
not enforced by the State (king.)[16]
The Irish laws managed a number of modern public
institutions within the private sphere.
Consider the institution of suretyship, for instance. Within Irish law, there were three kinds
of suretyship: the man who guaranteed his own property for his principalÕs
default, the man who pledged his own person and freedom by becoming a hostage
to the defrauded party if the principal defaulted, and a man of higher rank
than the principal who pledged his honor price in compensation for the insult
to the honor of the defrauded. Most
every transaction required a surety; the more important transactions required
all three. This seems to have
resulted in a number of people having a very real interest in seeing that the
principal fulfilled his duty. The
chances of the principal being able to defy the law with impunity were very
slight.[17]
While one may believe that there must have been
no sense of law and order without a public enforcement mechanism, one should
note that fear of the compulsive power of the State is not one of the main
reasons at all why the majority of men obey laws. The legal system present in early
Ireland, for instance, is built not on State sanctions, but on the power of
traditional custom. This custom has
been formulated and applied by a learned professional caste (the Brehons) that
functions and commands obedience.
Of course lawlessness existed; lawlessness exists in our own modern
society despite the strength of the State (hence the great number of attorneys!). But as Binchy notes, Òfar more important
that the threat of State enforcement in the minds of a small, rural, and
patriarchal community was the veneration due to hallowed ancestral tradition. There was also the enormous prestige of
the learned class who were custodians and practical interpreters of
tradition. In the absence of state
backing, they showed remarkable ingenuity in devising methods of procedure
which would compel the average citizens É to keep the rules. Perhaps, indeed, their very success
hindered the evolution of public justice by diminishing the need for it.Ó[18] With no need for a stronger State role
in justice, why create a public enforcement institution?
[1] ÒThe Linguistic and Historical Value of the Irish Law TractsÓ D. A. Binchy—Proceedings of the British Academy. Oxford University Press. Oxford. 1943.214
[2] Early Irish Society, edited by Myles Dillon. ÒSecular InstitutionsÓ by D.A. Binchy. Published for the Cultural Relations Committee of Ireland by Colm OÕLochlainn Dublin: At the Sign of the Three Candles 1954, pg 53
[3] ÒThe Linguistic and Historical Value of the Irish Law TractsÓ D. A. Binchy—Proceedings of the British Academy. Oxford University Press. Oxford. 1943. Pgs 213-214
[4] Early Irish Society, edited by Myles Dillon. ÒSecular InstitutionsÓ by D.A. Binchy. Published for the Cultural Relations Committee of Ireland by Colm OÕLochlainn Dublin: At the Sign of the Three Candles 1954pg 53
[5] 209-210
[6] Some Comparative Aspects of Irish Law
Alfred Gaston Donaldson. Duke University Press, Durham, NC. 1957
[7] Modern Irish cases referencing Brehon Law: Foyle and Bann Fisheries Ltd. v. Attorney General (1949) 83 I.L.T.R. 29 at page 41
[8] ÒThe Linguistic and Historical Value of the Irish Law TractsÓ D. A. Binchy—Proceedings of the British Academy. Oxford University Press. Oxford. 1943. Pg 219
[9] http://www.ucc.ie/celt/published/T102030/index.html
[10] http://www.ucc.ie/celt/published/T102030/index.html
[11] 59
[12] 59
[13] 58
[14] 59-60
[15] 61
[16] 60
[17] 63-64
[18] 63